Saturday, 28 March 2015
Thursday, 12 March 2015
Company Returns: Factors Determining Amount
This post relates to academic research regarding investor returns in the form of dividends, capital gain and share repurchase premiums.
Dividends - In light of equity investors, Baker, Farrelly and Edelman (1985)
propose that the optimal dividend policy exists, refuting Miller and Modigliani’s
(1961) argument that dividend policies equally affect the company’s stock
price and cost of capital. This is because Miller and Modigliani’s theory holds
numerous restrictive assumptions, such as perfect capital markets, which fail
to apply in reality. The optimal dividend payout is a balance between present
dividends and long term growth that maximises share price.
Lintner (1956) theorises
that despite management’s valorisation of a long-term target payout ratio, a steady
increase in dividends is optimal. Decisions involving changes to dividend
rates likely to have short-term reversal are overlooked in favour for partial
adjustments towards the target ratio to smooth dividends. Such predictability
ensures no short-term detrimental effects on stock price as it aligns with
investor expectations. This behavioural model thus implies dividend change is a
function of targeted dividend payout minus the previous period’s payout times
by an adjustment factor, where the target is a proportion of the present
period’s earnings. Therefore firms determine divident amount through a
partial adjustment model, favoured by the market as it stabilises and grows
dividends per share.
The amount of returns is
further determined through the interrelationships between investment, financing
and dividend decisions (Baker and Powell 1999). An insinuation of Miller and
Modigliani (1961) is that dividend payouts remain a residual decision, hence
the amount used financing investments from retained earnings determines
dividend payments. This means if future investment opportunities are abundant,
then dividends will be minimal if paid at all.
Dividends are
ultimately affected by earnings and cash flow per share, the latter calculated
by dividing net income with a weighted average of outstanding common shares and
the sum of net income, net working capital, depreciation divided by the same
denominator respectively. Consler, Lepak and Havranek (2011) found cash flow
per share has been found as a better determinant than earnings per share, as it
is less sensitive to accounting manipulation, unlike earnings. Nonetheless Liu,
Nissim and Thomas (2007) assert earnings forecasts better explain equity valuation
than operating cash flows. This is explained by the constant dividend growth
formula used to value stocks, as it implies investors maintain their
investments if firms are able to demonstrate evidence of a record of steady
dividend payments, and cash dividend payments terminate from significantly
negative earnings (Fama and French 2001).
Ultimately cash flow facilitate earnings, explaining the correlation of
earnings with cash dividends (Bali, Ozgur and Tehranian 2008). Likewise, the
moving average of revenue is correlated with the present value of future
dividends (Campbell and Shiller 1988).
High payout
protects against crises as investors continue supplying funds despite a fall in
the share price. Conversely, it can limit the firm’s capacity for growth as it
has fewer resources for investment. Such an impact is maximised if they
experience difficulties in debt financing. Hence the amount of dividends takes
into account an ideal balance between meeting short term shareholder
expectations and retaining sufficient funds for long term investment
opportunities. The majority of managers in Decourt and Procianoy’s study (2012)
emphasised on net profit as the most significant factor in dividend decisions,
indicating variations in dividends imply their future expectations over
profitability as a drop in dividend growth suggests lower expected earnings.
External factors also affect dividend decisions, such as interest rate and
exchange rate variations. The decrease in interest rates causes a decrease in
debt, and 14% of executives agree this stimulates increases in dividend
distribution. Economic crises likewise affect the dividend distribution,
suggesting that firms are concerned with the widespread implications of a fall
in dividends. Executive renumeration also influences the timing of dividend
distribution, as firms that reward executives on the basis of profit distribute
annual dividends whilst this observation tends to fall in firms that reward on
other conditions.
Moreover,
Griffin (2010) argues there exists an inverse relationship between dividend
amount and a company’s stock liquidity, suggesting companies decide on higher
dividend payments to compensate for a lack of liquidity. For illiquid stocks,
investors increase waiting times for buyers and this pressures them to accept
lower prices, allowing dividends to act as an income source. Meanwhile, liquid
stocks are able to form artificial dividends for the investor, as they are able
to sell stocks in a speedier time frame with minimal transaction costs.
Liquidity also extends the possible positive net present value investments
available as it minimises cost of capital (Becker-Blease and Paul 2006),
confirming the inverse relationship since increased investing due to high
liquidity reduces dividend amounts. Investors have a dividend preference based
on stock liquidity due to trading friction inherent in financial markets
(Banerjee et al. 2007), contrasting Miller and Modigliani’s (1961) assumptions
of frictionless markets in Dividend Irrelevance Theory which posits investors
are indifferent to dividends versus capital gain. They argue in frictionless
markets, dividends reduce the end value of existing shares as the dividend
stream is deterred to attract external capital from which future dividend
payments are derived.
Local market
liquidity additionally influences amount of returns since investors demand
higher expected returns on assets sensitive to liquidity, particularly in
emerging markets (Bakaert et al. 2007). Liquidity declines before expected
announcements and after unexpected announcements due to the political and
economic volatility of emerging markets (Graham et al. 2006). Hence in such
cases dividend amount increases.
Despite
dissimilar macro and micro influences, firm fundamentals and government
involvement, the inverse relationship between dividend amount and liquidity
extends to a global level. In Canada, over 70% of companies are owned by a
small group of concentrated holders in a family operated pyramid structure,
whilst over 70% of US companies are widely held, translating to more liquidity
and hence greater dividends paid out in Canada (Baker et al. 2007). Griffin
(2010) further found such a relationship occurs greatest in smaller firms,
implying the size of the firm affects how well the firm is able to realise and
react to the investors’ liquidity needs. Moreover, the dividend payment is also
based on the country’s relations with the US stock market, where stock markets
closely connected to the US exhibit a stronger negative relationship between
stock liquidity and dividends as investors are willing to replace their home
country’s stocks for US stocks if desired liquidity is not provided.
Share
repurchase premiums - Contrastingly, Lucke
and Pindur (2002) report shareholder returns in share buy-backs depend on the
techniques employed in share repurchase. Such techniques include open-market
(stock being bought back at current prices), fixed-price self-tender (offer
lasting a specific period of time to purchase pre-determined amount of shares
at premium) and Dutch-auction offers (firm specifies price ranges of tenders
for greater success). If the intention was to usurp greater control and
ownership, firms would offer a control premium, that is, a return to investors
higher than the share’s fair value (Stulz 1988). This is due to the created
wealth from value creation and value information, so the new value is P1 = (P0*N0+dW)/N0 where
P1 is the new share price, P0 is the original market value, N0 is the number of
shares, W is wealth.
The
premium is determined by wealth creation plus the original share price added
with the firm’s intrinsic value given the fixed price tender. It is also
influenced by the full information premium, which is paid in addition to the
intrinsic value of the firm resulting in a transfer of wealth towards tendering
shareholders to compensate for the opportunity cost of capital gain (McNally
1998). As a result stock prices rise due to an
imbalance between higher shareholder demand than supply, stimulating capital
gain for shareholders whom lack interest in selling (Bagwell and Shoven 1989).
Lücke and Pindur (2002) assert the premium combined with the expected new share
price in fact results in a share price higher than both. However when the
repurchase offer expires such capital gain decreases for the remaining
investors. Thus if all shareholders tender, then wealth creation is equally
shared, eliminating shareholder wealth transfer. Financial derivatives
intensify such returns. Put options, for instance, allows speculation with
greater leverage on the post-tender price. Rather than investing in
a company’s equity, investors have the option to invest in a firm’s debt.
Bonds - When investors
purchase company debt instruments, the amount of returns provided is dependent
upon on the characteristics of debt. For corporate bonds, the most common
form of corporate debt, the return level is determined by the market once these
characteristics have been decided by the firm, and is equal to the yield to
maturity of the bond. The yield is initially set at the market price for
the instrument’s risk level by adding a default premium to the risk-free rate
of return (Babbel, Merrill and Panning 1997),
resulting in the bond yield spread (Moeller and Molina 2003). The
default premium (which determines the credit spread) is based largely on the
credit rating assigned to the debt instruments by a credit agency (Purda 2011).
The factors that the company can influence in
determining the amount of returns is limited primarily to its capital
structure, financial policy and liquidity. Internationally, companies are
inclined to issue debt as the value of interest tax shields increases the value
of the firm, due to the Cost of Debt Capital =
Coupon Rate on Bonds (1 - tax rate), making the after-tax WACC
= rd(1-Tc)D/V + reE/V. However, in Australia
with the imputation tax system the tax advantages of debt is decreased
(Pattenden 2006), adding to the costs of financial distress in reducing the
benefits of debt financing. Rajan and Zingales (1995) found that debt
ratios are dependent on four main factors: size, tangible assets, profitability
and market to book, hence each company has a different ideal capital structure
to maximise value.
In analysing specific debt issues, credit rating
agencies first assess company credit rating and then further interpret the
terms and conditions of the debt security, the relative seniority of the issue
with regard to past debt issues and priority of repayment in the event of
default, and the existence of external support or credit enhancements (Standard & Poor’s 2014). Hence the
company can influence the rate of return by deciding on the characteristics of
its debt instruments which will influence their credit ratings, including the
time to maturity (Purda 2011).
Following the issue of debt, bond market prices
and yields will continually fluctuate, influencing the return investors receive
should they decide to not hold the asset to maturity however, this is not
within the control of the company (Aonuma and Tanabe 2011). Prices are
influenced as investors continually assess the debt instruments’ variable
credit quality and investment merit, analysing shifts in the economic
environment as well as entity, industry and debt-specific changes (Standard and
Poor’s 2014). Thus the relationship between inflation and interest rates upon
bond yield and spot price is particularly important in determining the level of
returns investors receive (Aonuma and Tanabe 2001).
Sources (part I & II):
Aonuma, K. and
Tanabe, T. 2001, ‘An Estimation Model for the Term Structure of Yield Spread’, Asia - Pacific Financial Markets, vol.
8, no. 2, pp. 137-165, Proquest Central, 215208434.
ASX Ltd. 2014, Dividend Prices, ASX Limited, <http://www.asx.com.au/asx/markets/dividends.do?by=asxCodes&asxCodes=bhp&view=all>
ASX Ltd. 2014,
Dividend Prices, ASX Limited, <
http://www.asx.com.au/asx/research/companyInfo.do?by=asxCode&asxCode=lyc#dividends>
Attig, N. 2005, ‘Balance of power’, Canadian
Investment Review, vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 6-12.
Babbel,
D.F., Merrill, C. and Panning, W. 1997, ‘Default risk and the effective
duration of bonds’, Financial Analysts
Journal, vol. 53, no. 1, pp. 35-44, Proquest Central, 219239308.
Bagwell,
L. S. and Shoven, J. B. 1989, ‘Cash distributions to shareholders’, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, vol. 3, no. 1, pp. 129-140.
Bakaert, G., Harvey, C. and Lundblad, C. 2007, ‘Liquidity and expected
returns: lessons from emerging markets’, The
Review of Financial Studies, vol. 20, no. 5, pp. 1783-1797.
Baker, H. K., Farrelly, G. E. and Edelman, R. B. 1985, ‘A survey of
management views on dividend policy’, Financial
Management, vol. 14, no. 3, pp. 78-84.
Baker, H.K. and
Powell, G.E. 1999, ‘How corporate managers view dividend policy’, Quarterly
Journal of Business and Economics, vol. 38, no. 2, pp. 17-35, ProQuest
Central, doi: 194736665.
Baker, K., Saadi, S., Dutta, S. and Gandhi, D. 2007, ‘The perception of
dividends by Canadian managers: new evidence’, International Journal of Management Finance, vol. 3, no. 1, pp.
70-81.
Bali, T.G., Ozgur, D. and
Tehranian, H. 2008, ‘Aggregate earnings, firm-level earnings, and expected
stock returns’, Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, vol. 43, no. 3, pp. 657-84.
Banerjee, S., Gatchev, V. and Spindt, P. 2007, ‘Stock market liquidity
and firm dividend policy’, Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis, vol. 42, no. 2, pp. 369-384.
Becker-Blease, J. and Paul, D. 2006, ‘Stock liquidity and investment
opportunities: evidence from index additions’, Financial Management, vol. 35, no. 3, pp. 35-48.
Bell, N. 2014,
‘The iron-ore led recession?’, Intelligent
Investor, 13 October, <http://www.intelligentinvestor.com.au/2014/10/macro-iron-ore-led-recession/>
Benartzi, S., Michaely, R. and Thaler, R.
1997, ‘Do changes in dividends signal the future or the past?’, The Journal of Finance, vol. 52, no. 3,
pp. 1007-34.
Bhattacharya, S. 1979, ‘Imperfect information, dividend policy, and the
bird in the hand fallacy’, Bell Journal
of Economics, vol. 10, no. 1, pp. 259-270.
BHP
Billiton 2014, BHP Billiton Limited, Melbourne, <
http://www.bhpbilliton.com/home/investors/shareholderinfo/Pages/Dividends.aspx>
BHP Billiton 2014, BHP Billiton successfully completes A$60 billion
off-market buy-back of BHP Billiton limited shares, media release, 11
April, <http://www.bhpbilliton.com/home/investors/news/Pages/Articles/BHP-Billiton-Successfully-Completes-A$6-0-Billion-(US$6-3-Billion)-Off-Market-Buy-Back-of-BHP-Billiton-Limited-Shares.aspx>
BHP Billiton
Limited credit rating 2014, Moody's Investors Service Inc., <https://www.moodys.com/credit-ratings/BHP-Billiton-Limited-credit-rating-120000>
BHP Billiton
Limited: Long-term Debt and Solvency Analysis 2014, Stock Analysis on net, <http://www.stock-analysis-on.net/NYSE/Company/BHP-Billiton-Ltd/Ratios/Long-term-Debt-and-Solvency>
Black, F. 1976,
‘The dividend puzzle’, Journal of
Portfolio Management, vol. 2, pp. 5-8.
Brealey,
A., Myers, S. and Allen, F. 2014, Principles
of Corporate Finance, 11th ed., McGraw-Hill/Irwin, New York.
Cambell, J. Y. and Shiller,
R.J. 1988, ‘Stock prices, earnings, and expected dividends’, The Journal of Finance, vol. 43, no. 3, pp. 661-76.
Campbell,
C. J., Ederington, L. H., and Vankudre, P. 1991, ‘Tax shields, sample-selection
bias, and the information content of conversion-forcing bond calls’, The
Journal of Finance, vol. 46, no.
4, pp. 1291-1324, ProQuest Central, doi: 194707245.
Chambers, M.
2014, ‘BHP Billiton shares take hit over lack of buyback’, The Australian, 20 August, <http://www.theaustralian.com.au/business/mining-energy/bhp-billiton-shares-take-hit-over-lack-of-buyback/story-e6frg9df-1227030525213>
Chunn, J. 2014,
‘Your BHP buyback primer’, Australian
Financial Review, 22 May, <http://www.afrsmartinvestor.com.au/p/shares/your_bhp_buyback_primer_zeW6wD78iPNzQM8UN04TrJ>
Consler, J.,
Lepak, G.M. and Havranek, S.F. 2011, ‘Earnings per share versus cash flow per
share as predictor of dividends per share’, Managerial Finance, vol.
37, no. 5, pp. 482-488, ProQuest Central, doi: 861089482.
Decourt, R.F.
and Procianoy, J.L. 2012, ‘The payout decision-making process of Brazilian
listed companies: a CFO survey’, Revista Brasileira de Finanças, vol.
10, no. 4, pp. 461-498, ProQuest Central, doi: 1347611638.
Dignan, J.H.
2003, ‘Non-default components of investment-grade bond spreads’, Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 59, no.
3, pp. 93-97, Proquest Central, 219251543
Easterbrook, F. H. 1984, ‘Two agency-cost explanations of dividends’, American Economic Review, vol. 74, no.
3, pp. 650-658.
Evans,
J.P., Evans, R.T. and Gentry, J. A. 2003, ‘The decision to repurchase shares: a
cash flow story’, Journal of Business and Management, vol. 9, no. 2, pp.
99-123, ProQuest Central, doi: 211508419.
Fama, E. and French, K. 2001, ‘Disappearing dividends: changing firm
characteristics or lower propensity to pay?’, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 60, no. 1, pp. 3-30.
Geske,
R. 1979, ‘The valuation of compound options’ , Journal of Financial
Economics, vol. 3, no. 7, pp.
63-81, ProQuest Central, doi: 231724069.
Graham, J., Koski, J. and Loewenstein, U. 2006, ‘Information flow and
liquidity around anticipated and unanticipated dividend announcements’, The Journal of Business, vol. 79, no. 5,
pp. 2301-2320.
Griffin, C.H.
2010, ‘Liquidity and Dividend Policy: International Evidence’, International
Business Research, vol. 3, no. 3, pp. 3-9, ProQuest Central, doi:
822229524.
Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H. 1976, ‘Theory of the firm: managerial
behavior, agency costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 3, no. 4, pp. 305-360.
Ker, P. 2014,
‘Iron ore slide won't stop BHP, Rio boosting payouts: CFS’, Sydney Morning Herald, 9 October, <http://www.smh.com.au/business/mining-and-resources/iron-ore-slide-wont-stop-bhp-rio-boosting-payouts-cfs-20141009-113jqk.html>
Kish,
R. J. and Livingston, M. 1993, ‘Market reactions to callable and noncallable
debt issues’, Journal of Applied Business Research, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 1-11, ProQuest Central,
doi: 227573461.
Koch, A. S. and Sun, A. X.
2004, ‘Dividend changes and the persistence of past
earnings changes’, The Journal of Finance,
vol. 5, no. 1, pp. 2093-116.
Lamont, O. 1998, ‘Earnings
and expected returns’, The Journal of
Finance, vol. 53, no. 5, pp. 1563-87.
Li, K. and Zhao, X. 2008,
‘Asymmetric information and dividend policy’, Financial Management, vol.
37, no. 4, pp. 673-694.
Lintner, J. 1956, ‘Distribution of incomes of corporations among
dividends, retained earnings and taxes’, American
Economics Review, vol. 46, no. 2, pp. 97-113.
Liu, J., Nissim, D. and
Thomas, J. 2007, ‘Is cash flow king in valuations?’, Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 63, no. 2, pp. 56-68.
Lücke, M. and
Pindur, D. 2002, ‘Riding the hat curve - why shareholders should tender their
shares in fixed price tender repurchase programs’, Finanzmarkt und
Portfolio Management, vol. 16, no. 3, pp. 358-377, ProQuest Central,
doi: 1113330024.
Lynas
Corp Ltd. 2014, Bloomberg, <http://www.bloomberg.com/quote/LYC:AU>
Lynas
Corporation 2014, Dispatch of Prospectus
and Entitlement and Acceptance Form, 9 October, <http://www.asx.com.au/asx/research/companyInfo.do?by=asxCode&asxCode=lyc%3E>
Lynas
Corporation: shareholder entitlement offer
2014, podcast, BRR Media, Australia, 1 October, <http://www.brrmedia.com/event/127486/amanda-lacaze>
Lynch, J. 2014,
‘BHP buyback on the cards, analysts predict’, Sydney Morning Herald, 19 February, <http://www.smh.com.au/business/mining-and-resources/bhp-buyback-on-the-cards-analysts-predict-20140219-33000.html#ixzz3G1bGvtcr>
Mason, M. 2014,
‘Australian shares suffer as global fears return’, Sydney Morning Herald, 8 October, <http://www.smh.com.au/business/markets/australian-shares-suffer-as-global-fears-return-20141008-1137ye.html>
Mayers,
D (1998), ‘Why firms issue convertible bonds: The matching of financial and
real investment options’, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 47, no. 1, pp. 83-102, ProQuest
Central, doi: 231737837.
McCann, D. and Olson, G. T.
1994, ‘The linkage between dividends and earnings’, The Financial Review, vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 1-14.McNally, W.
1998, ‘Who wins in large stock buybacks – those who sell or those who hold?’,
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, vol. 11, no. 1, pp. 78-88.
Miller, M. and Modigliani, F. 1961, ‘Dividend policy, growth, and the
valuation of shares’, Journal of Business,
vol. 34, no. 4, pp. 411-433.
Miller, M.H. and Rock, K.
1985, ‘Dividend policy under asymmetric information’, The Journal of Finance, vol. 40, no. 4,
pp. 1031-51.
Morningstar
2014, ‘Lynas Corporation to hold a 5:14
renounceable entitlement issue of 887.07m shares at 8 cents to raise $70.1m’, Morningstar, 29 September, <http://www.morningstar.com.au/Stocks/SignalGNews/20140929/313995>
Neems, M. 2014,
‘BHP upbeat about post-demerger dividend’, The
Australian, 26 September, <http://www.theaustralian.com.au/business/latest/bhp-upbeat-about-post-demerger-dividend/story-e6frg90f-1227071768052?nk=1307a55b6ac5be2757d7a411bbf9a362>
Pattenden,
K. 2006, ‘Capital structure decisions under classical and imputation tax
systems: a natural test for tax effects in Australia’, Australian Journal of Management, vol. 31, no. 1, pp. 67-92, Proquest
Central, doi: 200612120.
Purda, L. D.
2011, ‘Assessing credit or determining quantity? The evolving role of rating
agencies’, Journal of Applied Finance,
vol. 21, no. 2, pp. 20-37, Proquest Central, doi: 1352861007.
Rajan,
R. and Zingales, L. 1995, ‘What Do We Known about Capital Structure? Some
Evidence from International Data’, Journal
of Finance, vol. 50, pp. 1421-1460.
Roddan, M. 2014,
‘Lynas shares sink on FY loss’, Perth Now,
29 September, <
http://www.perthnow.com.au/business/breaking-news/lynas-widens-full-year-loss/story-fnn9c0ha-1227073634268>
Rozeff, M. S. 1982, ‘Growth, beta and agency costs as determinants of
dividend payout ratios,' Journal of
Financial Research, vol. 5, no. 3, pp. 249-258.
Soter, D., Brigham, E. and Evanson, P. 1996, ‘The dividend cut heard
round the world: the case of FPL’, Journal
of Applied Corporate Finance, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 4-15.
Standard
& Poor’s Financial Services LLC 2014, Guide
to Credit Rating Essentials, <https://media.ratings.standardandpoors.com/documents/SPRS_Understanding-Ratings_GRE.pdf>
Stephens,
C. and Weisbach, M. 1998, ‘Actual share reacquistions in open-market repurchase
programs’, Journal of Finance, vol.
53, no. 1, pp. 313-33.
Stulz, R. 1988,
‘Managerial control of voting rights – financing policies and the market for
corporate control’, Journal of Financial
Economics, vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 25-54.
Tabtieng,
N. 2013, ‘Motivations for share repurchase programs and the effect of share
prices on managerial decisions to end share repurchase programs in Thailand’, International Journal of Business and
Social Science, vol. 4, no. 10, pp. 1-10, ProQuest Central, doi:
1437608897.
Tanquintic-Misa,
E. 2012, ‘Australia’s Lynas receives $225m financial backing to complete
Malaysian rare earths plant’, International
Business Times, 25 January, <http://au.ibtimes.com/articles/287109/20120125/another-dilemma-australia-s-lynas-receives-225m.htm#.VDvvU7U0WuJ>
Thatcher, J. S. 1985 ‘The choice of
call provision terms: evidence of the existence of agency costs of debt’, Journal of Finance, vol. 40, no. 2, pp. 549-561, ProQuest Central, doi:
194703544.
Wall,
L. D., Robbins, E. H., and Schatzberg, J. D. 1988, ‘Callable bonds: a
risk-reducing signalling mechanism - A comment; A reply’, The Journal of
Finance, vol. 43, no. 4, pp.
1291-1324, ProQuest Central, doi:194706099.
Wansley,
J., Lane, W. and Sarkar, S. 1989, ‘Management's view on share repurchase and
tender offer premiums’, Financial
Management, vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 97-109.
Young,
A. 1969, ‘Financial, operating and security market parameters of repurchasing’,
Financial Analyst Journal, vol. 1,
no. 1, pp. 123-128.
‘Why
Lynas Corp is struggling; The Great Rare Earth Shortage is truly over 2014, Forbes,
8 March, <http://www.forbes.com/sites/timworstall/2014/08/03/why-lynas-corp-is-struggling-the-great-rare-earth-shortage-is-truly-over/>
Shareholder Return: Dividends and Repurchases
This post relates to academic research that studies the multitude of factors affecting management decisions regarding how returns are distributed to stakeholders.
Investor returns not only constitute dividends, but also capital gain. The latter is used mainly as it presents financial benefits for the corporation, as it is considered a financial expense, reducing the firm’s income tax. On the other hand, shareholders face increased tax. This suggests management interests influences dividends and therefore highlights an agency problem between shareholders and executives (Decort and Procianoy 2012).
Nonetheless investor expectations are taken into consideration in dividend policy. For instance, stable dividends are preferred and expected by investors due to the minimal risk in returns (Lintner 1956). A deviation from shareholder expectations stimulates an immediate market reaction that can reduce the market capitalisation of the company. Despite this, the Miller and Modigliani theory asserts dividends and profit have no significant relationship in perfect markets; rather, the risk of its assets is key to determining the value of a firm. However, market imperfections such as agency conflicts, transaction costs and asymmetrical information are factors that influence dividend decisions as then it affects the value of the firm (Miller and Modigliani 1961). Baker and Powell (1999) argue dividend policy has an influence on firm value, and such dividend relevance is due to bird in the hand, tax preference, signalling and agency explanations.
Bird in the Hand Explanation - This argument states dividends act as a certain investor return relative to capital gains, hence provides a tangible incentive to ensure investors do not abandon the stock. Due to lower risk of dividends, companies should maximise dividend payout ratio and set high dividend yield to increase share price, since companies with a track record of dividend payments are traded at a premium (Fama and French 2001). However, Bhattacharya (1979) argues otherwise, stating that maximising the present dividend payout ratio will reduce the stock’s ex-dividend price. Therefore such a strategy will fail to maximise company value by lowering risk of future cash flows.
Signalling Explanation - Dividend policy communicates information to investors regarding the company’s earnings and future prospects. Dividend announcements reveal management’s perspective of the company’s future profitability (Miller and Rock 1985). Asymmetry of information implies internal management hold greater information than external investors, hence dividend changes reduce such asymmetry by allowing investors to analyse the stock price. Battacharya (1979) considers the shareholders’ horizon as a finite period, hence a high dividend payout signals it has invested in projects with high net present value therefore providing sufficient cash flow to honour the shareholder’s expectations. Dividends therefore provide information regarding both past and present earnings (Benartzi et al. 1997), suggesting market responses to changes in dividends are delayed responses to previous changes in earnings (Koch and Sun 2004).
Firms that use signalling tend to experience lower growth and higher variability in earnings but higher increases in asset turnover, are smaller and are less dependent on debt financing in the long term (McCann and Olson 1994), suggesting these are also internal factors influencing the allocation of dividends. However such dividend changes are ambiguous until the market is able to recognise between firms in the growth stage and firms with minimal investment opportunities (Easterbrook 1994). Soter, Brigham and Evanson (1996) report that when FPL Group announced a 32% cutback in its quarterly dividend, the market reacted negatively through a 20% stock price decline. However, analysts realised such a dividend policy was strategic to enhance long-term growth opportunities and financial flexibility as opposed to signalling distress.
Li and Zhao (2008) also repudiate signalling theory and find ceteris paribus, information asymmetry causes firms to distribute smaller and less dividend payments and are less likely to increase such returns, casting doubt on the practicality of signalling theory.
Tax-Preference Explanation - Tax preference theory argues investors favour fund retention over dividend payout as otherwise only specific investors, that is, those subject to minimal tax rates, would be attracted to invest. The tax clientele effect applies to stocks with low payouts, as they should only attract higher taxed investors. Such investors favour capital gains, hence minimising dividend payout will maximise stock prices.
Agency Explanation - Jensen and Meckling (1976) advance the agency theory, which posits dividend policy acts as an incentive for management to reduce agency costs derived from the conflict of interests between internal management and shareholders. Agency costs increase if management exploit the perquisites out of retaining funds, and investing them in a sub-optimal manner. As maximising dividend payout reduces internal cash reserves controlled by management and increases external financing into the company’s capital structure, external capital suppliers therefore subject the company to increased scrutiny, diminishing the likelihood of suboptimal investments (Rozeff 1982). Thus dividend payments provide a mechanism to monitor management performance and align them to shareholder interests.
Premiums - Share repurchase is another form of investor return as the firm exchanges cash for shares owned by investors. Under the signalling theory, providing such a return occurs if the firm believes share prices are under-priced on a fundamental basis, or if they desire to increase their earnings per share (Stephens and Weisbach 1998), particularly if there were tax savings in adding debt to capital structure, increasing leverage (Young 1969). However, Wanscly, Lane and Sarkar (1989) finds three factors more directly affecting share repurchase decisions are to eradicate shareholders’ structure to minimise administrative burden of having minority shareholders, defend against takeovers, or if they have excess cash with limited investment opportunities. Excess cash results in the agency problem as management may invest in sub-optimal investments, hence the firm must pay out the excess cash through either stock repurchase or dividend payout. Due to the reputational penalties involved in volatile dividend payouts, management have greater incentive to retire stock instead. This also allows them to provide shares for internal programs such as exercising stock options or employee bonus and retirement programs.
Case Studies
Share Repurchase
Lynas Corporation, currently experiencing a deteriorating economic condition and financial distress due to the firm’s inability to cover operating and capital costs (Forbes 2014), have not issued any share buyback offers. Tabtieng (2013) states terminating this mechanism of return provision is influenced by stock price changes. If the company’s stock price increased from its current level of 8.3 cents (ASX 2014), Lynas Corporation could resell to gain, unless they value ownership structure over financial statement content. This is because in terms of financial statements, surges in inappropriate retained earnings whilst outstanding and nonoutstanding shares are reduced means shareholder equity is on par with previous periods. However, the company gains through an ability to pay out dividends or maintain a buffer against economic downturns. Under the signalling theory, providing such a return would signal that Lynas shares are underpriced on a fundamental basis, or they desire to increase their earnings per share (Stephens and Weisbach 1998). As a result, we believe Lynas Corporation should consider the positive impacts of share repurchase as an investor return instrument.
Likewise, Lynch (2014) focuses on BHP’s minimisation of gearing levels to 30% and their goal to maintain annual capital expenditure at $15 billion, which can both trigger share repurchase and investments. BHP Billiton, one of the world’s largest producers of major commodities, is a company in a relatively ‘strong’ financial position, posting an underlying attributable net profit of US$7.8 billion for the half year ended 31 December 2013 (BHP 2014). While share repurchase enables debt reduction, we believe that due to the internal competition for available capital and growing share price, BHP should favour long term investor returns from growth investment rather than short term cash dividends or buybacks.
During the December 2013 half year BHP issued a four tranche Global Bond, providing investors with fixed levels of returns from 2.050% to 5%, and a floating rate option, depending upon investor risk preference (BHP 2014). Its Senior Floating Rate Notes due in 2016, provided investors with a return only 25 basis points above US Dollar LIBOR due to the high credit rating of the company and its senior debt as A1, an upper medium grade investment quality, highlighted in Moody’s BHP Biliton Limited Credit Rating (2014). It could be inferred that BHP’s chosen capital structure, with debt to equity ratio currently 0.4, is successful in achieving minimum debt financing costs, while providing sufficient cash flow to meet its commitments. However, Heath Jansen, Citi analyst, posits that the main limitation BHP faces in increasing their payout ratio (including repurchases) was their net debt, which once cut to $20 billion, should increase dividends by 7%.
Stock repurchase has a stronger practical application in BHP. According to BHP Billiton (2011), their repurchase of 4.4% of its issued equity capital was priced at a 14% discount at $40.85 per share. This, like Lynas, can improve earnings and cash flow per share and return on equity given the lesser amount of issued capital, benefiting all shareholders regardless of their participation. For instance, the investors’ capital proceeds accumulate to $9.31, $9.03 of it being the difference between the tax value and the buyback price. The significant factor affecting the buyback was external, being the oversubscription by investors which introduced the need to scale back tenders. Shareholders who sold back their stocks at 14% discount had a priority allocation of shares repurchased before such a scale back was applied.
BHP’s recent announcement of a buyback despite failure to execute suggests it acts as a marketing mechanism, to facilitate a shareholder friendly image (Lücke and Pindur 2002). Chambers (2014) suggests the buyback deferral provides predictability in future cash returns. Capital losses have also been prevented by investor anticipation of BHP’s buyback, as seen by its uncorrelated trajectory with iron ore prices (Chunn 2014). Such a decision not to deliver however has stimulated downgrades by Credit Suisse, a response that we agree with, as in the long run BHP cannot trade above its core valuation. BHP therefore valued a short term shareholder friendly reputation over the negative implications of uncertainty surrounding its capital management.
Dividends
BHP Billiton supports optimal dividend policy in terms of their progressive payout model, where they increase or at least preserve their base dividend for each payment (BHP 2014). Despite their recent profit collapse of 30%, BHP still managed to increase its dividend by 2 cents, up from $US0.57 to $US0.59 (Mason 2014). In fact, ceteris parabus, lower dependence on the mining sector due to declining iron ore prices translates to a free cash flow pre-dividend payout of $10 billion; a margin sufficient to rebase dividends upwards by 5%-10% in the next financial year (Ker 2014). However, Lynas Corporation has not provided such returns, in fact they have refrained from paying any dividends due to their decline in financial performance (ASX 2014). Lynas Corporation’s actions still support the significance of the optimal cumulative dividend model, as cutting back on dividends has produced a greater negative reaction relative to a predictable dividend payout ratio (Jose and Stevens 1989).
Moreover, Neems (2014) reports that BHPs demerger resulted in returns in the form of shares in the new company and involved a transferral of only minimal debt so as to not override equity holder returns. We disagree with their current dividend policies, instead recommending management should look to increasing the dividends at a faster rate. BHP’s dividend yield is a mere 3% at current market prices, which combined with relatively costly stocks that have underperformed recently, leaves investors expecting higher returns (Mason 2014).
Their decision to retain their progressive dividend payout model means the dividend decision remains a residual decision dependent on cash reserves. However, BHP’s estimation that the company loses $135 million with each incremental dollar fall in iron ore prices questions the remaining reserves (Bell 2014), placing emphasis on the formulating of a long-term market share strategy to appease investor return demands. Colonial First State approximates that in 2014, there was a $300 billion fall in capital expenditure in the resources sector (Ker 2014), resulting in long term supply shortages. However, continuously investing in BHP’s asset base will increase long term supply. The fact that this contradicts shareholder demand for dividends and buybacks highlights the need for BHP to deliver returns in another form such as discounted shares or a renounceable rights offer.
Contrastingly, Lynas Corporation has opted for such returns, partly due to their lack of dividends from financial distress. Lynas Corporation: shareholder entitlement offer (2014) reports on an offer in which 150 million new shares to institutional investors raised $83 million and existing shareholders were given a renounceable offer of 5 new shares priced at 9 cents a share, 2.5 cents lower their previous market price for every 14 shares already held. The subsequent market selling resulted in speculative capital gains before the share price dropped down to 9 cents.
Further, levering the firm through a strict and conditional senior loan facility of $225 million provides investors security in the event of further debt raising, as 50% of debt finance will first be used for partial investor repayment until the principal falls to $125m. (Lynas Corporation 2014). My recommendation for Lynas Corporation management involves a stronger focus on restructuring loans to amend Lynas’ debt amortization schedule to align it with planned future profitability (Roddan 2014), whilst reaping in the additional funds raised from the discounted share placement. Therefore this will improve liquidity, debottleneck operations and effectively transition the company from a start up stage to a growth stage through funding further investments (Morningstar 2014).
Singaporean Dollar: Forecasts and Reasons
The perception of Singapore as a favorable investment haven due to its high ratings on economic growth, low government corruption and transparency contrasts to their weak underlying economic fundamentals. Its fragility is mainly derived from its dependence on the cost of capital remaining low or growing at a relatively slow and consistent rate. That is, if US rates increase earlier than expected the SGD dollar will slump. Why? The problem originates from the US Fed's quantitative easing approach undertaken from 2009-2013. Whilst the US' quantitative easing consequences were intended for domestic growth purposes, the stimulus created bubbles in foreign emerging economies.
The SIBOR (Singapore Interbank Offered Rate) is linked to the US Federal Funds Rate in order to reduce volatility in the exchange rate. Therefore low Fed rates become a direct channel to form Singapore's credit bubbles. Since the SIBOR sets mortgage and loan prices, cheap credit meant household debt to GDP soared by 32% from 2005-2014. Singapore's property market prices also rose by over 50% from pre-GFC prices, now making it the third most expensive real estate market after Canada and Hong Kong. In fact, The Economist reports a 60% overvaluation of the Singaporean property market against the long term mean. If this asset bubble is popped, the banking sector will also suffer as half the banks' credit portfolios consist of general property loans, with a third being mortgages. Recently, the mean Singaporean mortgage rate has remained at approximately 1%. An increase of just one more percentage would result in interest costs more than covering the principal. Moreover, since the majority of these loans currently use floating interest rates, mortgage repayments will rise and reveal unsustainable debt once the Fed Rate increases to its historical average of between 3-6%. In fact, the prospect of a US interest rate hike for the first time in nine years was revealed today, mainly based on the fact that the number of job postings was the highest in fourteen years. As the Singaporean economy specialises in finance and property, effects are compounded, with the potential to mirror the post 2008 Irish economic crisis (where property values collapsed) and the 2008-2011 Icelandic crisis (where the banking system collapsed).
However, I do acknowledge that whilst the bubble is correlated with US monetary policy, the rate of return to average interest rates will be likely slow, allowing time for adjustments in Singapore. This centralises the risk on rates increasing before analyst expectations. Either or, conveying a bearish sentiment on the Singaporean dollar using long term call options is the best way to make returns from rising US rates and its consequences.
The SIBOR (Singapore Interbank Offered Rate) is linked to the US Federal Funds Rate in order to reduce volatility in the exchange rate. Therefore low Fed rates become a direct channel to form Singapore's credit bubbles. Since the SIBOR sets mortgage and loan prices, cheap credit meant household debt to GDP soared by 32% from 2005-2014. Singapore's property market prices also rose by over 50% from pre-GFC prices, now making it the third most expensive real estate market after Canada and Hong Kong. In fact, The Economist reports a 60% overvaluation of the Singaporean property market against the long term mean. If this asset bubble is popped, the banking sector will also suffer as half the banks' credit portfolios consist of general property loans, with a third being mortgages. Recently, the mean Singaporean mortgage rate has remained at approximately 1%. An increase of just one more percentage would result in interest costs more than covering the principal. Moreover, since the majority of these loans currently use floating interest rates, mortgage repayments will rise and reveal unsustainable debt once the Fed Rate increases to its historical average of between 3-6%. In fact, the prospect of a US interest rate hike for the first time in nine years was revealed today, mainly based on the fact that the number of job postings was the highest in fourteen years. As the Singaporean economy specialises in finance and property, effects are compounded, with the potential to mirror the post 2008 Irish economic crisis (where property values collapsed) and the 2008-2011 Icelandic crisis (where the banking system collapsed).
However, I do acknowledge that whilst the bubble is correlated with US monetary policy, the rate of return to average interest rates will be likely slow, allowing time for adjustments in Singapore. This centralises the risk on rates increasing before analyst expectations. Either or, conveying a bearish sentiment on the Singaporean dollar using long term call options is the best way to make returns from rising US rates and its consequences.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)